by Ahmed
Abdul-Kareem Saif
Doctoral Candidate in the Department of Politics,
University of Exeter, England.
This article was first published in
AL-MASAR Journal, Volume 1, Number 1 (winter) 2000, pp. 15-32.
SINCE
the establishment of the unification in May 22, 1990, democratic process has functioned in an unstable political
environment. The political arena has been characterised by a struggle
for power swinging from co-operation to a large-scale war. In a
democratic country, probably no political institution shapes the
political landscape more than its electoral system and its
political parties. Democracy in Yemen, however, has been affected
by many factors, among them the party and electoral system.
This paper, therefore, examines these two variables and shows
their impact on the parliament in particular and democracy in
general.
1. Electoral System
General Election Law No. 27/1996 has adopted the
first-past-the-post (FPP) system with single-member constituencies
[1]. All election affairs are organised technically by
the Supreme Election Committee (SEC), a body charged with the task
of preparing for and conducting all elections. This system formula
states that the candidate who obtains the most votes wins and all
votes for the other candidates are effectively wasted [2]. The 1993
and 1997 parliamentary elections showed that the FPP system
favours the largest parties.
Supporters of this electoral system contend it suits Yemen's
circumstances. With the high rate of illiteracy, voters can
recognise and choose their candidates on a personal basis. This
also provides transparent, easy, and straightforward elections.
Moreover, this gives room for independents to be represented in
the Parliament [3]. Findings suggest that 69.8 per cent of the MPs
support the existing electoral system, which brought them in.
Opponents contend that such a system in a traditional society
like Yemen's would increase the importance of kinship preferences,
which would deepen the sub-national identity at the expense of
party electoral programmes. This downgrading the level of
Parliament's professionalism. This system also disfavours small
parties, depriving them of representation in Parliament. Opponents
instead call for proportional representation (PR), claiming that
it minimises personal and financial influences, allows political
parties to form coalitions, gives priority to programmes, and
enables parties to choose the most qualified, not the most
socially influential, candidates [4].
With regard to representation, however, the existing FPP system
shows shortcomings. For example, in the 1997 election, at the
constituency level, 116 MPs won with less than half (some as few
as 23 per cent) of all votes in their constituencies. At the
national level, as (Table 1) shows, when adding up all the
constituencies' results to get an overall state of the Parliament,
all MPs got 55 per cent of all votes cast and 33.7 per cent of all
registered eligible voters.
Table 1:
Impact
of the FPP on representation
Elections of |
Voters Registered |
Voters Cast |
% |
Total Votes |
% |
1993 |
2,682,457 |
2,271,126 |
84.7 |
NA* |
NA* |
1997 |
4,606,932 |
2,824,752 |
61.3 |
1,554,725 |
55 |
* NA: Data not available.
To highlight the state of the parties in the Parliament after
the 1997 election, it has been found that regarding the ratio of
seats to votes, the GPC (General Peoples's Congress) got 63.54 per
cent of seats based on achieving 43.14 per cent of total votes. By
comparison, the Islah party got 17.73 per cent of seats and 23.38
per cent of votes [5]. It is obvious the FPP system enables large
parties to win every seat with a simple majority, leaving the
minority totally underrepresented. In this sense, elections could
be free but not fair. Based upon a simple majority, a candidate
could win by a slight edge, as little as 23 per cent of the vote
in a constituency.6 Having gained a landslide victory, the GPC
seeks no change in the electoral system. The only hope left for
small parties lies in a concentration of support in certain
regions rather than distribution across the country.
The FPP system produces a majority government. In both
elections held in Yemen small parties won 12 and 5 seats in the
1993 and 1997 elections, respectively. However, in a nascent
democracy such as Yemen's, this system probably provides a stable
majoritarian government that allows for a certain co-operation
between the Parliament and the government. In the short run this
is possibly desirable to allow democratic institutions to
consolidate and institutionalise further.
2. Party System
After the unification in 1990 Yemen had over forty political
parties, later decreasing to fifteen in order to meet the
requirements of Law No. 66/1991 governing organisation and
political parties. Among the fifteen parties, nine pre-date the
existence of the Parliament.
The prominent feature is the fluid state of most of these
parties. The parties weaken by the traditional context, fragmented
social structure, paternalism, and personification of politics
that affected parties' organisation and cohesion. In the
historical evolution of the parties, severe repression pushed them
underground, which has also contributed to weakening intra-party
democracy and to the absence of a rational mechanism for
decision-making.
Yet, Unlike most Western political parties, most large parties
in Yemen did not originate in legislative bodies. They had their
roots in local organisations or in the nationalist movement. So
these parties, mainly the GPC and the YSP (Yemeni Socialist
Party), emerged as single dominant ones benefiting from their
links with the founding of the state. Thus, they have retained a
known electorate cemented by using state patronage to reinforce
their strength. During the interim period both the GPC and the YSP
used their control of the state to reward their supporters with
jobs and money. After the 1994 war, the GPC continues benefiting
from this advantage. By comparison, most of the newly created
parties had to start from scratch and appeal to a floating
electorate [7], resulting in marginalization of the small parties, as
shown in (Table 2).
Table
2: Parliamentary Seats by Party
|
Parliamentary
Election (1993)
|
Parliamentary
Election (1997)
|
Party
|
Cand.
|
Votes |
%
|
Seats |
% |
Cand.
|
Votes |
%
|
Seats
|
% |
GPC |
275 |
640,523 |
29 |
123 |
40.9 |
233 |
1,175,343 |
43.2 |
187 |
62.1 |
IND. |
1945 |
606,201 |
27.2 |
47 |
15.6 |
1399 |
805,636 |
29.6 |
56 |
18.6 |
YSP |
210 |
413,984 |
18.9 |
56 |
18.7 |
B |
B |
B |
B |
B |
Islah |
189 |
382,545 |
17.4 |
63 |
20.9 |
188 |
637,738 |
23.4 |
53 |
17.6 |
ANB |
156 |
80,362 |
3.7 |
7 |
2.3 |
46 |
9,439 |
o.35 |
0 |
0 |
ASB |
NE |
NE |
NE |
NE |
NE |
25 |
20,409 |
0.75 |
2 |
0.7 |
Haqq |
63 |
18,659 |
0.85 |
2 |
0.7 |
26 |
5,587 |
0.2 |
0 |
0 |
CN |
25 |
6,191 |
0.28 |
1 |
0.33 |
15 |
2,755 |
0.1 |
0 |
0 |
DN |
17 |
4,576 |
0.2 |
1 |
0.33 |
30 |
9,601 |
0.3 |
0 |
0 |
PUNO |
89 |
52,303 |
2.37 |
1 |
0.33 |
80 |
55,438 |
2.1 |
3 |
1 |
Total |
2,970 |
2,205,344 |
100 |
301 |
100 |
2,042 |
2,721,946 |
100 |
301 |
100 |
Keywords: B (boycotted); Candid. (Candidates); NE (did not
exist then); IND (independents); ANB (Arab National Ba'ath); ASB
(Arab Socialist Ba'ath); CN (Corrective Nasserite Party); and DN
(Democratic Nasserite Party).
Table 2 suggests a highly volatile party system that reflects
the fact that voters changed their preferences between two
consecutive elections. This elaborates levels of loyalty to party,
people's awareness of the political process, party organisation,
and degree of democracy consolidation. Electoral volatility is
measured by half the sum of the absolute percentage difference
between the votes received by each party in two consecutive
elections.8
Therefore, the formula of electoral volatility in Yemen is:
( [62.1-40.9] + [18.6-15.6] + [18.7-0.00] + [20.9-17.6] +
[2.3-0.00] + [0.7-0.00] + [0.7-0.00] + [0.33-0.00] + [0.33-0.00] +
[1-0.33] ) / 2 = 51.23/2 = 25.61%
Historical evidence shows a negative relationship between
democratic consolidation and electoral volatility. In West
European elections between 1885 and 1985 average volatility was
8.6 per cent [9]. The lower it is, the more likely that the electoral
arena is well established. The high volatility of the Yemeni party
system demonstrates a fractionalised party system. The volatility
value increased slightly under the effect of the YSP's boycotting
the last election; nonetheless it remains high.
With regard to party organisation, this explains the
relationship between the parliamentary party and the party
organisation. So far, only eight parties have been represented in
the last two parliaments. Five parties are leftist (the three
Nasserite parties, the Ba'ath, and the YSP), two are Islamist
(al-Haqq and the Islah), and from the right is the GPC. Apart from
the three biggest parties (GPC, YSP, and Islah), other parties
have been, in all, represented by only seventeen MPs in the last
two Parliaments. The MPs of the small parties are very disciplined
and show strong commitment to their parties' policies. Their small
number means that their parties and the media put extra pressure
on them to be genuine representatives for their parties. Thus,
those MPs' behaviour does not reflect systematically the
organisation of their parties.
On the other hand, the three big parties show different trends.
The MPs representing these parties viewed intra-party discipline
as follows: 53 per cent of the GPC call for much higher levels of
discipline; 56 per cent of the YSP call for much less; and 60 per
cent of the Islah express their satisfaction with the present
level of discipline. In all parties, the majority of MPs said
there are no sanctions available to their parties against them in
case of deviation from party polices, and at most they receive
blame [10].
The fluid structure of the GPC is explained by the fact that it
has no definite ideology. It was founded as a political umbrella
that consists of different political trends and factions. After
unity it continues with the purpose not to represent but to
govern. In this sense the GPC is a catchall party and as a ruling
party it controls the state-owned media, through which it
communicates with its electorate. Another factor contributing to
the low level of its discipline is the background of its MPs. They
are mainly from amongst the long-standing politicians and powerful
tribal leaders. Many social figures were recruited to the GPC
after they won their seats as independents. Members of the GPC,
therefore, ask what their party can do for them, not what they can
do for their party. Usually, state financial aid distributed by
the GPC goes to the party bureaucracy, not to the party in
Parliament. Because of this the GPC's MPs evacuated the floor in
November 1, 1998, protesting the GPC President's decision to
provide ministers but not MPs with new cars. The loose
organisation of the GPC dictates its MPs' actions, which are
characterised by individual preferences and discretion. As a GPC
MP points out, the GPC's government does not consult its MPs on
policies, so the MPs are not obligated to support them in
Parliament [11]. However, the position of the President as head of
the GPC limits the MPs from going far. On vital issues, the
President makes personal contacts with the MPs to ensure their
consistency [12].
In contrast, the YSP comes at the other end of the spectrum.
Attitudes of its MPs tend toward lessening the strict internal
discipline. As a mass party ruled South Yemen centrally for about
three decades, it is accustomed to the top-down commands. Patterns
of recruitment also enhanced this tendency whereby strong loyalty
to the party outweighs other issues. It mainly depends on
peasants, workers, and other deprived strata of society. Given the
fact that all syndicates were controlled by the single then party
existing, promotion was in accordance with loyalty to the party
and to factions within it. After unity, YSP members have adhered
more to their party as they perceive it to be the only guarantor
of their political future in a more diverse and complicated arena
than was the South. Moreover, the close link between the GPC and
the Islamic-oriented Islah party makes the YSP more vulnerable.
Therefore, after the 1993 elections the MPs of the YSP showed
strong commitment to their party in order to counterbalance the
majority bloc of rivals. It was a struggle for the MPs of the YSP
to maintain their privileges as a former ruling party and a
partner in the new state that required a highly disciplined cadre.
The Islah party falls at the mid-point between the GPC and the
YSP. As a newly emerged party it benefited to a great extent from
the struggle between the other two parties. Though it overtly
sided with the GPC for social, political and ideological reasons,
this was not politically free. The Islah represented tribal and
Islamic interests, so its MPs come mainly from these two factions.
The tribal MPs behaved as those in the GPC and mainly for the same
reasons, whereas the Islamist MPs behaved similarly to those of
the YSP for the same motives. This explains the reasonable level
of discipline within the party. The relationship between the party
and its MPs is characterised by individual discretion on the
general issues and by commitment to the party's policies on the
clear Islamic issues.
Variation in the relationships between parties and their MPs
supposes different procedures for agenda-setting. In the light of
the aforementioned relationships, it is logical to find different
degrees of participation for MPs in agenda-setting in accordance
with their responses to their parties' policies. Findings show
that 61.8 per cent of MPs say the politburo and party leaders have
the most say in party policy and 20 per cent refer that to party
convention. This emphasises Michels' "iron law of
oligarchy", which states that an organisation is dominated by
its leadership [13].
In the same vein, though from a different perspective, Von
Beyme believes the balance of power between the central party
organisation and the parliamentary party has shifted to the
disadvantage of the latter [14]. Empirical studies, however, do not
support Michels' and Von Beyme's positions that all parties would
develop dominance by extra-parliamentary parties. There is still
substantial scope for other possibilities [15]. Other research
concludes:
'Doctrinaire parties experienced high degree of centralisation
and involvement with low levels of complexity and factionalism in
their organisation and fared poorly at the polls while maintaining
strong cohesion in the legislature and engaging in many
activities. On the other hand, parties that we call 'mobilising'
tend to do well in elections, while engaging in several
non-campaign activities although showing little legislative
cohesion. Organisationally, mobilising parties tend to be highly
complex but not very centralised, and they have little
factionalism and low levels of membership involvement' [16].
Different MPs' behaviour, then, goes beyond party leadership
domination and points to the effect of other factors. Al-Saqqaf
argues that the main factor influencing MPs in Yemen is the media
[17]. Despite that, 66.4 per cent of the MPs said the media are
not important. The media, however, probably influence MPs
indirectly through influencing parties' election manifestos. Yet,
two other factors are still important in relations between MPs and
their parties. The first is the MPs' personal experiences and
attitudes. The second is the type of the issues raised: the more
the issues are clear and have a direct effect on people, the more
MPs are responsive regardless of their parties' points of view.
Nomination is certainly not the exclusive preserve of the party
at the centre. There are no rules or law in Yemen establishing
criteria for nomination. Apart from the YSP, all parties seek
nominees who have the best chance of carrying their
constituencies. The YSP boycotted the 1997 election, making it
difficult to observe changes in its selection, as happened with
the other left-to-centre parties, which modified their criteria
for nomination from loyalty and ideology to the ability of a
nominee to win a constituency. In general, because of the
traditional society based on kinship networks, only 57.7 per cent
of the MPs said they are representing a political party.
Therefore, nomination to a great extent is based on social and
personal characteristics.
Linked to this is the incumbency rate, which was 21 per cent in
the 1993 Parliament and 42 per cent in the 1997 Parliament. The
latter had a higher rate for two reasons. First, most of the MPs
elected to the 1993 Parliament were new because the MPs of the
1990 Parliament were appointed and among them only 12.9 per cent
had been re-elected. The second factor is the absence of the YSP
in 1997 because it boycotted the election, providing a space for
others for re-election. Overall, among the incumbents 42.3 per
cent belonged to the GPC, 25.4 per cent to the YSP, 15.2 per cent
to the Islah, 13.5 per cent were Independents, and 1.8 per cent
for each were from the Ba'ath and Nasserite parties.
For those who were denied re-nomination, it never happened
because of their stand on a policy question. A considerable number
of nominees are chosen at local level because of their status,
which makes parties endorse their nomination. Many MPs also
competed as independents and later different parties competed to
affiliate them. The GPC is the most successful in recruiting
independent MPs because of the privileges it provides as a ruling
party. Weak control over nomination deprives parties of a powerful
instrument for imposing ideology and policy conformity on MPs.
.../next
page
|